본 연구에서는 1976년부터 2020년까지의 분기별 자료를 이용해 과연 경제성장률이 명목 또는 실질 단기금리와 어떤 관계를 갖고 있는지를 살펴보았다. 레짐스위칭 모형 추정결과 두 변수 간의 시변적인 동조화 확률은 전반적으로 높은 양(+)의 값을 가지나 외환위기 전후로 크게 하락한다. 인과관계분석에 따르면 GDP 성장률이 떨어지는 경우 외환위기기간을 제외하고는 금리가 하락하는데 금리 하락폭은 외환위기 이전 기간에 비해 외환위기 이후 기간에 훨씬 크며 통계적으로 유의적이다. 또한 동일한 크기의 충격에 대한 금리 하락폭은 외환위기 이후부터 코로나 사태 이전 기간 동안에 점차 커지는 경향을 보인다.
This paper analyzes the relationship between the real GDP growth rate and nominal or real short-term interest rates using quarterly data from 1976 to 2020. First of all, depending on how the real interest rate is measured, real interest rates show a big difference in the period before the currency crisis, while relatively similar movements in the period after the currency crisis. Meanwhile, the regime switching models show that high growth and high interest rates in the period before the currency crisis rapidly change to low growth and low interest rates in the period after the currency crisis. According to the time-varying regime switching model, the probability of time-varying synchronization between the two variables not only has a positive (+) value even before the currency crisis, but also has been on the rise overall until recently, although it has fallen significantly just before and after the currency crisis.
This study also examines whether the economic growth rate can affect interest rates through the causal relationship analysis as well as correlation and synchronization analyses. The estimation results of the linear VAR model with crisis dummy variables and trend terms indicate that interest rates fall when economic growth falls, as claimed by the new classical school. In the case of the time-varying VAR model as well as the linear VAR model, interest rates fall significantly in both nominal and real interest rates due to the impact of falling economic growth during the post-crisis period compared to the pre-crisis period. This seems to be related to a major change in monetary policy, which changed price stability from the previous monetary target to a single final goal under the sixth revision of the Bank of Korea Act on December 31, 1997, and disclosed the call rate as an operating goal from May 1999. However, even though the economic development clause(Article 3, Paragraph 2), which had been stipulated together with the stability of the currency value(Article 3, Paragraph 1) before the 6th revision of the Bank of Korea Act, was omitted in the 6th revision, the economic growth rate and interest rate seem to have a closer positive relationship after the revision. This fact means that the central bank is always concerned with growth rates and use its operating target, as the Taylor rule shows, regardless of the text of the law.
In addition, the rate of decline in interest rates in response to shocks of the same size tends to gradually increase during the period from the post-currency crisis to before the outbreak of COVID-19. These empirical analysis results have important implications in relation to monetary policy at a time when the potential growth rate continues to decline. If interest rates fall more as the growth rate decreases, they face a zero lower bound problem as interest rates get closer to zero. In this case, as the aggregate demand curve goes upward rather than downward, the automatic adjustment function of the economy is lost, and if left unattended, the economic recession will worsen. In this situation, advanced countries such as the United States have overcome this difficulty through non-traditional monetary policies such as quantitative easing, credit easing, and forward guidance. But it is unclear whether the Korean economy, which is a small open economy and the won is not the key currency, can implement these policies without major side effects.
UCI(KEPA)
간행물정보
: 사회과학분야 > 경제학
: KCI등재
:
: 계간
: 1225-9489
: 2714-0288
: 학술지
: 연속간행물
: 1988-2022
: 486
저작권 안내
한국학술정보㈜의 모든 학술 자료는 각 학회 및 기관과 저작권 계약을 통해 제공하고 있습니다.
이에 본 자료를 상업적 이용, 무단 배포 등 불법적으로 이용할 시에는 저작권법 및 관계법령에 따른 책임을 질 수 있습니다.
개인회원가입으로 더욱 편리하게 이용하세요.
아이디/비밀번호를 잊으셨나요?